The horizon is not so far as we can see, but as far as we can imagine

Tag: Privatization

Continued Privatization

Last year I wrote a fairly long article on why everything was being privatized: Western elites are in a duel where those who lose are squeezed out of the actual elite. They may still be rich, but they don’t have power. This duel is particularly dire in the US and the UK, but affects all Western countries to some extent and Anglo countries severely.

Since the real economy isn’t growing as much as it used to (and certainly less than measured), they have to steal from the commons and from government.

Consider the British Mail privatization of 2015, done by the Conservatives and the Liberals: the mail service had been owned by the Crown for five hundred years. Britain has privatized all its railways. Service has gone to shit. More literally gone to shit is the water system, where millions of tons of raw sewage are being dumped into Britain’s rivers and coast, while the water utilities pay massive dividends.

In Ontario, where I live, alcohol sales were, for generations, restricted to the “Liquor Control Board of Ontario” and the “Beer Store.” Are most recent Prime Minister, ex-drug dealer (this isn’t a slur, it’s a fact) Doug Ford, has reduced the duopoly,  and continues to do so. The most recent step is to allow corner stores to sell beer. Thing is, the LCBO and Beer store routinely make billions for the government.

(The Beer Store is run by Ontario’s brewers, they had a contract that ended in 2025 and the 225 million is buying out that contract early)

So this is going to cost Ontario a low estimate of 800 million or so a year. There’s also the fact that the LCBO and Beer Store are very good at checking IDs, so there’ll be a lot more under-age drinking, though I personally don’t care all that much. But social conservative types, one would think, would.

Ontario, since Covid, has a huge problem with hospital waiting times, both for emergency and regular services. Perhaps instead of giving away government money, Ford should spend it on that?

But the point is simple: this is privatization of profits, and ordinary people will pay for it: it has to result in increased taxes, reduced spending or increased public debt.

You get what you support. If you like my writing, please SUBSCRIBE OR DONATE

Privatization Is Always A Ripoff

Water edition, from the UK

Analysis in 2020 found that privatised (sic) water companies paid £57bn in dividends to shareholders since their foundation in 1991 to 2019. Now they say they need better infrastructure to stop piping sewage into rivers, lakes, and sea.

Up here in Toronto, Canada, we privatized half our trash collection, dividing the city in half. The West has private collection, the East has public. When it went into force, the arguments were strong: private was cheaper. Now, a few years later:

Oh, hey, what a surprise. It costs more and they pay workers less than the City does.

Let’s keep this simple, as free market fundamentalists who usually understand nothing about markets often say, “There is no such thing as a free lunch.” TANSTAAFL.

Private companies have to make a profit. Public companies do not. Private companies are not miraculously more efficient, to be cheaper than public companies, they have cut costs. Often that is wages, other times it is not paying to maintain or upgrade infrastructure required to keep sewage out of the water.

For anything where we know how to do it; where there is actually little room for innovation, and where the service provided is about the same for everyone (this includes almost all universal or near universal insurance, all utilities including water and power and internet) public provision is more efficient and private provision can only be cheaper by cutting costs you don’t want cut. That includes, of course, pushing costs into the future: the trash company in Toronto knew it’d raise prices in the future, it undercut for a few years to get its foot in the door.

Once you do privatize it can be difficult to take something back public. You’ve sold the assets, and the people you sold them to are making money and don’t want to sell back. Especially at lower levels of government you may not be able to force them to, or force them to at a reasonable price. In addition, they now have a constituency of rich people who need them to continue (investors, executives) and who can use their money to lobby and bribe officials.

As a rule, most privatizations are fraud, and the politicians who do them are corrupt, helping out friends and donors and doing well out of the process. Most politicians who do this should be treated as criminals and thrown in prison for defrauding the public, corruption and fraud.

(About half of the neoliberal agenda initiated by Thatcher and Reagan was and is just “privatize everything you can so the rich can get richer.” It’s not capitalism, it’s rentierism and corruption and makes economies weaker, not stronger.)

TANSTAAFL. There is no free lunch, if a private company can make money off a public asset, it’s been sold to them for less than its worth, and the people who will pay in the end are taxpayers.

If it is a public good, it should be provided publicly.


(My writing helps pay my rent and buys me food. So please consider subscribing or donating if you like my writing.)

 

 

The Chimerical Growth of GDP and Privatization

Modern economies are often measured in terms of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Look up the definition of GDP and you’ll come up with something like this: a country’s GDP is the total value of all finished goods and services in a country in a year plus exports, minus imports.

Consider this, if a parent takes care of their children, is that included in GDP?

No, it isn’t.

What if the children are taken care of by a nanny or day care worker?

Then yes, it is part of GDP.

Either way the work gets done, the children are taken care of. But if they are looked after by someone who is paid for it, it’s considered economic activity and if not done for money, it isn’t considered economic activity. Studies show, and our own common sense tells us, that as a rule, children cared for by their own parents, especially when young, turn out better: healthier, less likely to commit crime later on, brighter, and so on. So, increasing GDP by paying to have children cared for reduces well being while increasing the size of the economy.

More money being spent, and more GDP, is not always good. Another commonly used example is that if a hurricane devastates a city, the rebuilding will increase economic activity, and GDP. This doesn’t mean we want hurricanes to wipe out cities. Keeping someone in prison costs more than sending them to university, that doesn’t, or at least shouldn’t, mean we prefer locking young men up to sending them to prison.

In the developing world GDP is often increased by moving from subsistence farming, which is to say, people growing their own food, to cash crop farming. Moving to cash crops, for various reasons, tends to push people off the land. They no longer grow their own food and now have to buy it. GDP increases because cash crops are sold for money, mostly to foreigners, and sometimes because a whole bunch of people now have to buy their food rather than growing most of it.

The theory behind this is that with the foreign currency earned by selling cash crops, the country can modernize, the displaced subsistence farmers will find jobs, and buy food. In practice, in many countries, the farmers have wound up in vast urban slums without jobs, food has to be imported from overseas, and what the UN euphemistically calls “food insecurity” spreads. There is a larger economy as measured by GDP, but more people are hungry, more people can’t support themselves, and malnutrition stunts the intelligence and growth of the generations to come.

Ironically, because there are only so many cash crops, and western “development experts” spent decades telling multiple countries to grow the same few crops, the price of the the crops often crashed. The end result of that was that countries wound up with trade deficits, and had trouble affording imported foods. (The IMF will then tell the government to stop subsidizing food. The result is predictable.) So you have the spectacle of Egypt, for millennia the breadbasket of the world, needing to import food, nor is it the only country which went from feeding itself to having to buy food. (check timing on this)

GDP is up, measurable economic activity is up, but much of the population is worse off, though certainly some people get rich.

Another way GDP and the money economy increased is through privatization. Imagine a road is sold to a private company. The people, in the form of the government, get a one time infusion of cash. The company receives an asset – the road, whose value comes from the ability to charge people to drive on it.

This increases the money economy in three ways:

  •  An asset can be borrowed against. The value of assets in the economy has just increased, and new capital can be raised by the owners of the road to do whatever they want with. This could be productive, investing in their business, or it could be used to pay the executives more money, or it could be used to buy back shares in an already existing company, raising share prices and increasing executive bonuses based on share price.
  • If not already a public company, the company can sell itself either to other private investors, or by issuing shares to the public. If they raise more money doing that than they spent buying the road, then they have a surplus which they can use to pay themselves or invest in some fashion. They could buy another company, invest in the business itself, branch out (perhaps putting up stores on the road), and so on. Once those shares are issued, people who own them have an asset, and they too can borrow against that asset, often for many times what the shares are worth.
  • The fees used to drive on the road. The road is an end product, this is GDP. The economy has increased in size.

All of this may sound good, but the price is obvious: people have to pay to drive on the road. While it’s strictly true that the public road was paid for, through taxes, that’s very different from having to pay a private company to drive a road. Because it is no longer free in daily practice, the road will be used less. Drivers will have to decide if the cost of driving on this particular road is worth it.

This will reduce economic activity. Say you were thinking of going out to eat. The cost is no longer gas+meal cost, it is now gas+meal cost+toll or perhaps the cost of taking roads which go to the same place, but less quickly. For some people, the cost will now be higher than the benefit. The restaurant loses a sale. So do other businesses.

By selling the road we have pumped up the economy in the short term, and created more assets which can be borrowed against (which is good if the money is used productively, but not if it isn’t) and we have given some specific people a way to make a profit in the future. But we have also reduced the benefits of the road for everyone else.

There are other types of privatization. Perhaps the government directly provides garbage pickup, using its own employees. Perhaps road repair, or police, or cooking food for troops, or car insurance, or the railways, or airports, or power generation, or clean safe water, or sewage removal and treatment, or parks.

Privatization can be good, there are services and goods which are better produced by markets, but widespread privatization is often a way of artificially pumping the private asset base of the economy. It looks good, it produces increased GDP and GDP per capita, but it often actually reduces welfare.

Privatization, then, often produces money and the chimera of economic growth, but not the happiness, sense of purpose and access to healthy levels of necessities which are supposed to be the purpose of growth and money.


If you enjoyed this article, and want me to write more, please DONATE or SUBSCRIBE.

Powered by WordPress & Theme by Anders Norén